Production theory for constrained linear activity models
Production theory for constrained linear activity models
Аннотация
Код статьи
S042473880024866-1-1
Тип публикации
Статья
Статус публикации
Опубликовано
Авторы
Lahiri Somdeb  
Должность: Adjunct Professor
Аффилиация: LJ University, School of Management Studies
Адрес: Индия,
Выпуск
Страницы
5-15
Аннотация

The purpose of this paper is to generalize the framework of activity analysis discussed in the paper by Antonio Villar without requiring any dimensional requirements on the activity matrices and by introducing a model of activity analysis in which each activity may (or may not) have a capacity constraint. We follow the usual nomenclature of input-output analysis for “the quantity of a good supplied to the consumers outside the production (or manufacturing) sector” and refer it as “final demand”. We obtain results similar to those in Villar concerning solvability, non-substitution and existence of efficiency prices. We apply our analysis and results to the two-period multisector activity analysis model with capacity constraints. The activity matrix is the difference between a non-negative output coefficient matrix and a non-negative input coefficient matrix, with the coefficients being measured in money units for each activity. Almost all the results obtained thus far get replicated in this macroeconomic context. However, some reformulations are required for issues related to existence of equilibrium price vector and as a consequence, issues related to efficiency prices via the non-substitution theorems. The corresponding concepts in this application refer to “inflation rate” vectors.

Ключевые слова
constrained, linear activity analysis, solvability, non-substitution theorem, efficiency prices
Источник финансирования
This paper is in honour of Professor Dipankar Dasgupta and Professor Pradip Maiti, who taught me Linear Production Models and Linear Programming respectively.
Классификатор
Получено
24.09.2022
Дата публикации
29.03.2023
Всего подписок
15
Всего просмотров
161
Оценка читателей
0.0 (0 голосов)
Цитировать Скачать pdf
Доступ к дополнительным сервисам
Дополнительные сервисы только на эту статью
Дополнительные сервисы на весь выпуск”
Дополнительные сервисы на все выпуски за 2023 год
1 1. Introduction
2 The purpose of this paper is to generalize the framework of activity analysis discussed in A. Villar (Villar, 2003) and obtain similar results concerning solvability. We generalize the model due to A. Villar (Villar, 2003), without requiring any dimensional requirements on the activity matrices and by introducing a model of activity analysis in which each activity may (or may not) have a capacity constraint i.e., a maximum level at which the activity can operate. This may be one way to accommodate meaningful non-linearities similar to that considered for input–output analysis in I. Sandberg (Sandberg, 1973).
3 In I. Sandberg (Sandberg, 1973), the input-output coefficients were assumed to be differentiable, which is very likely an approximation of the more realistic and practically applicable representation in which the input-output coefficients are piecewise constant. Minor, technical increments on the solvability result in Sandberg (Sandberg, 1973) can be found in P. Chander (Chander, 1983) and some references therein. Undoubtedly, piecewise constant input-output constants are more difficult to deal with mathematically than differentiable ones. Non-linearities are much easier to represent in the framework of linear activity analysis by introducing upper bounds — whenever there is a capacity constraint for the levels at which each such activity may operate. We do this by introducing a model of activity analysis in which each activity may (or may not) have a capacity constraint. In this paper we follow the usual nomenclature of input-output analysis for “the quantity of a good supplied to the consumers outside the production (or manufacturing) sector” and refer it as “final demand”.
4 It seems that in this significantly more general framework we are able to obtain the desired results concerning solvability and existence of an equilibrium price-vector under weaker assumptions than the corresponding requirements in A. Villar (Villar, 2003). The property that guarantees solvability has the following economic interpretation: Given two price vectors p, q a final demand vector and unit prices of operating capacity constrained activities, if the revenue from operating every unconstrained activity at unit level at price-vector p is no less than doing the same at price-vector q and if the revenue from operating a constrained activity at unit level at price-vector p is no less than doing the same at price-vector q plus the unit price of operating the activity then the value of the final demand at price vector p is no less than the value of the final demand at price-vector q plus the total cost of the capacities. In the context of the constraint linear activity analysis model, we call this property “weakly proper”. We also prove a version of the Non-Substitution Theorem that establishes the existence of “efficiency price-vectors” as a joint product. However, our Non-Substitutions Theorem — in spite of the generality of our model as compared to the one due to A. Villar (Villar, 2003) — requires that if there are capacity constraints, then there is a minimal subset of the set of capacity constrained activities that are always used up to full capacity, for the production of all producible final demand vectors. Further, these capacity constrained activities are the only ones whose capacities are binding for some producible final demand vector. Hence there is a clear dependence of the equilibrium price vector on the final demand vector (i.e. the vector of quantities supplied for non-manufacturing prices); unlike the conclusion of Sraffian economics1, and we are able to show this without using production functions. Our framework is a generalization of the one used in Sraffian economics.
1. See the sixth paragraph at: >>>>
5 In a concluding section of this paper, we apply our analysis and results to the two-period multisector activity analysis model with capacity constraints. Production takes place in the current period and the sale of goods outside the production system, takes place in a subsequent period. The activity matrix is the difference between a non-negative output coefficient matrix and a non-negative input coefficient matrix, with the coefficients being measured in money units for each activity. Almost all the results obtained thus far get replicated in this macroeconomic context. However, some reformulations are required for issues related to existence of equilibrium price vector and as a consequence, issues related to efficiency prices via the non-substitution theorems. The corresponding concepts in this application refer to “inflation rate” vectors, i.e., “equilibrium inflation rate-vector” and “efficiency equilibrium rate-vector” respectively. In the case of final demand for services (provided by the service sector) which do not require manufacturing, but are none-the-less measured in current producer prices, this may imply a difference between producer prices and the prices that consumers are required to pay for the services during the current period.
6 In what follows we will be making extensive use of mathematical results in Topics 2 and 3 — and therefore by implication results in Topic 1 — of Lahiri (Lahiri, 2022). Sometimes, when there is no scope for confusion, given two vector/points x and y in a real Euclidean space of the same dimension we use xy to denote that every co-ordinate of x is greater than or equal to the corresponding coordinate of y, x > y to denote xy, but x y (x is not equal to y), and x >> y to denote every coordinate of x is strictly greater than the corresponding coordinate of y.
7 2. Motivation
8 Consider a very simple production process which produces a single output (“corn”) from a single input (once again “corn”). In the classical or Leontief Input-Output (IO) Model one assumes that there exists a fixed positive constant a such that ax units of corn are required to produce x units of corn. The production process productive if and only if 0 < a < 1. However, in reality the assumption of a fixed input-out coefficient a is unrealistic. Fertility of the soil is not uniform. Hence, it is unreasonable to assume input-output coefficient remains constant for all levels of output.
9 Sandberg (Sandberg, 1973) suggested that the input-output coefficient(s) is(are) a differentiable function(s) of the gross output. Once again, differentiability of input-output coefficient appears to be an “unrealistic” assumption for actual production processes. Even if such an assumption is theoretically true, it is extremely difficult to invoke it for practical use in “production planning”. It is perhaps more realistic to assume that input-output coefficients are piece-wise constant. In what follows we generalize such an assumption and develop the theory that follows from it to the case of production with possibly more than one good.
10 The Sraffian conclusion of market prices being independent of the quantity “supplied” (which is referred to in the literature on input-output analysis as “final demand”) with fixed input-output coefficients and hence fixed unit costs of production with competitive factor markets, is not unreasonable at all in the “one good” setting, since that is precisely what is indicated by the intersection of any demand curve with a horizontal marginal cost (or perfectly competitive supply curve). However, in the more general setting with piece-wise constant input-out coefficients or piece-wise constant marginal cost functions, neither would the associated extension of the Sraffian linear model indicate such independence between market price and quantity supplied and nor would it be implied by the intersection of the market demand and marginal cost curves.
11 3. The Model
12 Consider an economy with m produced goods indexed by i = 1, …, m and n activities indexed by j = 1, …, n.
13 An mn matrix of real numbers is said to be non-zero, if it has “at least one non-zero entry”.
14 Note. The rank of a non-zero matrix is a positive integer.
15 Let M be a non-zero mn matrix of real numbers called an activity matrix which column j denoted Mj for j {1, …, n} denotes the amount of net output each good if the activity j is operated at unit level. Thus for I {1, …, m} and j {1, …, n}, the entry i of Mj denoted mij denotes the net output (of the produced good i if the activity j (or activity j) is operated at unit level. If mij is negative, then –mij is the amount of the produced good i used as net input, if the activity j is operated at unit level.
16 In what follows, unless otherwise stated, we shall use net output and output interchangeably. The same applies for net input and input.
17 An activity-vector is a column vector x R+n such that for all j {1, …, n}, the row j (or coordinate) of x, denoted xj, is the level at which activity j is operated.
18 A constrained linear activity analysis model (CLAAM) is a pair (M,<x-j|jW>) where M is an mn activity matrix and if W then <x-j|jW> is an array with x-j R++ being the maximum level at which activity j W {1 ,…, n} can operate, the possible levels of operation for activities in (1, …, n}\W being unbounded above. If W = , then a constrained linear activity analysis model with activity matrix M is (M, ).
19 In the case of (M, ) no activity has a capacity constraint.
20 Note. This is a very general formulation. In particular there could be non-negative mn matrices B, A such that M = BA.
21 A column vector d R+m \{0} is said to a final demand vector if for all I {1, …, m}, the row i of d, i.e. di represents the quantity of good supplied i for non-manufacturing/non-production purposes, i.e. quantity of the good supplied i to the consumers outside the production process.
22 The following is an example of an activity matrix, different from any in A. Villar (Villar, 2003) and any known to us otherwise (see chapters 6 and 7 of K. Lancaster (Lancaster, 1968)).
23 Example 1. Let C be a nn matrix of non-negative real numbers such that for all i, j{1, …, n}, cij which is the element (ij) of C, is a non-negative real number that denotes the level at which activity i is required to be operated – to produce enough of the m produced goods — so as to be able to operate activity j at unit level. Let B be a mn matrix of non-negative real numbers such that for all h {1, …, m} and I {1, …, n}, bhi is the element (hi) of B, denoting the (net) amount of good h that is produced with the purpose of satisfying final demand, if activity i operates at unit level.
24 Let M = B(I – C).
25 If x R+n satisfying xj x-j for all j W, if W and unconstrained otherwise, is an activity-vector then Cx denotes the level at which the activities are required to operate in order to “operationalize” the activity vector x. The remaining levels of activity vector (I – C)x are used to produce the “produced goods” in the amount B(I – C)x, provided (I – C)x R+n .
26 In what follows, unless otherwise stated or required, we will write ( M,<x-j|jW> ) to represent a CLAAM, with the implicit understanding that if W = , then the CLAAM reduces to or represents (M, ).
27 The following definition will prove to be important in the analysis that follows.
28 A price-vector is a vector p R+m \{0} where the coordinate i of p, denoted pi is the unit price at which the produced good i is sold in the market. Let w > 0 denote wage rate of labour.
29 4. Solvability of CLAAM
30 Given a CLAAM ( M,<x-j|jW> ) and a non-empty subset of activities J, we define the set Constrained Span ( M,<x-j|jW> , J), denoted CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) = {Mx Rm |x Rn with xj x-j for j W and xj = 0 for all j J}.
31 Thus, CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) Span (M, J).
32 If J = {1, …, n}, then CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) is written simply as CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) .
33 Let J be a non-empty subset of {1,…, n}.
34 The content of the following property is based on one due to Villar (Villar, 2003).
35 A CLAAM ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is said to be weakly proper for (a non-empty subset of activities) J, if for all pq R+m , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d   CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ( R+m \{0}) : [ pTMj jqTMj for all j WJ and pTMjqTMj for all j J\W implies pTdjWJαjx-jqTd].
36 We use (CLAAM ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is weakly proper for J and ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is a CLAAM weakly proper for J, or just ( M,<x-j|jW>,J ) is weakly proper for J interchangeably.
37 Weakly proper in the context of CLAAM has the following economic interpretation (if we interpret j as the unit cost of operating a capacity constrained activity jWJ):
38 if the revenue from operating every unconstrained activity in J at unit level at price-vector p is no less than doing the same at price-vector q and if the revenue from operating a capacity constrained activity in J at unit level at price-vector p is no less than doing the same at price-vector q plus the unit price of the capacity then the value of the final demand d at price vector p is no less than the value of the final demand d at price vector q plus the total cost of the capacities.
39 In the interpretation provided above we are assuming that capacities have an imputed price/shadow price given by the alphas up to the maximum that is possible.
40 A CLAAM M,<x-j|jW> is said to be weakly proper if it is weakly proper for {1, …, n}.
41 In particular, (by setting j = 0 for all j W) for all pq R+m and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ( R+m \{0}) : [pTMqTM implies pTdqTd].
42 Given a CLAAM M,<x-j|jW> the activity matrix M is said to be weakly proper if for all p, q R+m and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ( R+m \{0}) : [pTMqTM implies pTdqTd].
43 Clearly the activity matrix M is weakly proper if the CLAAM M,<x-j|jW> is weakly proper.
44 Since any point in Rm can always be expressed as the difference between two points in R+m the following is an immediate consequence of the definition of a weakly proper activity matrix.
45 CLAAM M,<x-j|jW> is weakly proper for J if and only if for all p Rm , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d( CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) )( R+m \{0}) : [pTM j ≥ 0 for all j WJ, pTMj ≥ 0 for all j J\W, implies pTdjWJαjx-j ≥ 0].
46 Note. The definition corresponding to weakly proper activity matrices in A. Villar (Villar, 2003) is equivalent to our definition of weakly proper activity matrices of CLAAM’s because A. Villar (Villar, 2003) requires Span (M) R++m  .
47 Lemma 1. Suppose CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m . Then ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is a weakly proper CLAAM for J if and only if p,qR++m , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d CS(M) R++m : [ pTMjαjqTMj jWJ and pTMjqTMj jW\J implies pTdjWJαjx-jqTd].
48 Proof. If ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is a weakly proper CLAAM for J, then it is easy to see that p,qR++m , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d   CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ) R++m : [ pTMjαjqTMj jWJ and pTMjqTMj jW\J implies pTd jWJαjx-jqTd].
49 Hence suppose that p,qR++m , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m : [ pTMjαjqTMj jWJ and pTMjqTMj jW\J implies pTd jWJαjx-jqTd].
50 Then as in the case of weakly proper CLAAM’s for J, we get in this case that for all p Rm , an array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m : [ pTMjj ≥ 0 jWJ , pTMj ≥ 0 jW\J , implies pTdjWJαjx-j0 ].
51 Suppose d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ( R+m \{0}).
52 By hypothesis CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m . Let d* CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m .
53 Now d* CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m implies td* CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m for all 1t>0.
54 Similarly, d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R+m implies (1–t)d + td* CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m for all 1t>0.
55 Thus, d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R+m implies (1–t)d + td* CS(M) R++m for all 1t>0.
56 Let < t(h)|h N > be a sequence of positive real numbers less than or equal to 1, converging to 0.
57 Clearly, the sequence < (1–t(h))d + t(h)d*|h N  > converges to d and for all h N , pT1t(h)d+t(h)d*0.
58 Thus pTd ≥ 0.
59 Thus, ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is a weakly proper CLAAM for J. ■
60 Proposition 1. ( M,<x-j|jW> ) is a weakly proper CLAAM for J if and only if for all final demand vectors d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) there exists x R+m satisfying Mx = d, xj x-j for j WJ and xj = 0 for all j J.
61 Proof. Let d be a final demand vector in CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) . For d = 0, clearly Mx = d, where x = 0 and further xj x-j for j W. Hence, we may suppose that dCS(M,<x-j|jW>,J)R+m\0.
62 (M,<x-j|jW>) is weakly proper for J if and only if there does not exist pRm , any array of non-negative real numbers <αj|jWJ> and dCS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) R++m satisfying pTMjaj0 jWJ , pTMj0 jW\J and pTdjWJαjx-j<0 .
63 Hence by Farka’s lemma, (M,<x-j|jW>) is weakly proper for J if and only if Mx = d, x R+n , xj x-j for j WJ and xj = 0 for all j J has a solution. ■
64 Note. Nowhere have we invoked any restriction on the size of the activity matrix or its rank, except that the rank of the activity matrix is positive. That leaves out the uninteresting case of M = 0. Thus, our framework is considerably more general than that of Villar (Villar, 2003).
65 An immediate consequence of the proposition above is that the requirement of n m in Villar (Villar, 2003) can be dispensed with not only for solvability problem in activity analysis, but also for the non-substitution theorem (theorem 5) in the same paper.
66 5. Existence of equilibrium price-vector
67 We will now present a similar generalization as above for the existence of an equilibrium price-vector for a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) .
68 Let Am+1 be a row vector in Rn with all co-ordinates strictly positive, where the entry in the jth column denoted am+1,j > 0, is the amount of the only non-produced good called “labour” that is used as input if activity j is operated at unit level. Let L- > 0 be the total initial amount of labour in the economy.
69 Recall that a price-vector is a vector p R+m \{0}. Let w > 0 denote wage rate of labour. At price-vector p and wage rate w the profit-vector at the pair (p,w) denoted πp,w=pTMwAm+1 .
70 A row vector v R+n is said to be profitable at wage rate w > 0, if there exists q Rm such that qTM = wAm+1 + v.
71 Note. The vector q in the definition of profitable vectors need not be non-negative.
72 A price-vector p is said to be an equilibrium price-vector at the wage rate w > 0 and row-vector v R+n if v = (p, w).
73 Recall that an activity matrix M is said to be weakly proper if for all p, q R+m and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) ( R+m \{0})( R+m \{0}) : [pTMqTM implies pTdqTd].
74 Proposition 2. Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) , suppose M is a weakly proper activity matrix and v is a profitable row vector at wage rate w > 0. Then there exists an equilibrium price-vector p at the wage rate w and row-vector v.
75 Proof. Since w > 0, Am+1 >> 0 and v ≥ 0, we get wAm+1 + v >> 0.
76 Since v R+n if there exists p R+m such that pTM = wAm+1 + v, then it must be the case that p R+m \{0}.
77 Since v is profitable at wage rate w > 0, there exists q Rm such that qTM = wAm+1 + v.
78 Towards a contradiction suppose that there does not exist p R+m such that pTM = wAm+1 + v. By Farkas’ lemma, there exists x Rm such that Mx R+m and (wAm+1 + v)x < 0.
79 Since M is weakly proper, Mx R+m implies that there exists y R+n such that My = Mx ≥ 0.
80 Now qTM = wAm+1 + v >> 0 and y ≥ 0 implies qTMy = (wAm+1 + v)y ≥ 0.
81 Thus My = Mx implies qTMx = qTMy = (wAm+1 + v)y ≥ 0.
82 On the other hand qTM = wAm+1 + v implies qTMx = (wAm+1 + v)x < 0, contradicting qTMx ≥ 0, that we obtained above.
83 Thus there exists p R+m such that pTM = wAm+1 + v and as we observed earlier this p R+m \{0}. ■
84 6. Non-substitution theorem
85 Recall that a final demand vector is a column vector d R+m \{0}.
86 Let J be a non-empty subset of {1, …, n}.
87 Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) , a final demand vector d is said to be producible by (activities in) J if there exists x R+n satisfying Mx = d, Am+1x L- , xj x-j for all j W, and xj = 0 for all j J. Clearly any such x must belong to R+n\ {0}.
88 It follows from proposition 1, that if (M,<x-j|jW>) is weakly proper for J, then any final demand vector d CS(M,<x-j|jW>,J) is producible by J, provided the requirement of labour to produce it does not exceed L- .
89 If J = {1, …, n}, then a final demand vector producible by J is said to be producible.
90 Hence the set of all final demand vectors producible by J is {Mx R+m \{0}|x R+n , xj x-j for all j W, Am+1x L- , and xj = 0 for all j J}.
91 Given a price-vector p, a wage rate w > 0, a producible final demand vector d, and x R+n satisfying Mx = d, the aggregate profit of the production sector is pTdwAm+1x. If the production sector intended to maximize profit, then it would be required to solve the following profit maximization problem: Find x to solve
92 pTdwAm+1xmax subject to Mx = d, Am+1x L- , xj x-j for all j W, x ≥ 0.
93 However, given the price-vector p and w, the above for a producible final demand vector is equivalent to solving the following linear programming problem denoted LP – d:
94 wAm+1xmin subject to Mx = d, –Am+1x ≥ – L- , –xj ≥ – x-j for all jW, x ≥ 0.
95 If y solves LP – d then y > 0 since d > 0. Thus Am+1y > 0.
96 The question that we are interested in is the following: If for some producible final demand vector, x* is an optimal solution for the minimization problem, then is it the case that for all final demand vectors producible by j|xj*>0, there exists an optimal solution for the minimization problem, such that the activities operated at a positive level at this optimal solution is a subset of j|xj*>0 ?
97 Given a producible final demand vector d, the dual of LP – d denoted DLP – d is the following linear programming problem: Find q Rm , an array of non-negative real numbers <hj|jW> and a real number ≥ 0 to solve:
98 qTdαL--jWhjx-j max     subject to qTMj-aAm+1,jhjwAm+1,j for all jW, qTMjαAm+1,jwAm+1,j    jW.
99 Suppose there exists a producible final demand vector d* and let x* be an optimal solution for LP – d*. By the Weak Duality Theorem for LP, there exists q* Rm , an array of non-negative real numbers <hj*|jW> and a real number * ≥ 0 such that:
100 I) q*TMj *Am+1,jhj* wAm+1,j for all j W,
101 Ii) q*TMj *Am+1,j wAm+1,j for all j W,
102 Iii) [q*TMj*Am+1,jhj*wAm+1,j] xj* = 0 for all j W,
103 iv) [q*TMj*Am+1,jwAm+1,j] xj* = 0 for all j W,
104 v) Mx* = d*,
105 vi) *[Am+1x*L- = 0,
106 vii) xj*x-j    jW,
107 viii) [xj*-x-j]=0    jW,
108 ix) [q*Td*α*L-jWh*jx-j]=wAm+1x*.
109 Since by (v) Mx* = d*, (iii), (iv) and (vi) implies [q*Td*α*L-jWh*jxj]=wAm+1x*.
110 [q*Td*α*L-jWhj*xj*]=wAm+1x* combined with (viii) implies [q*Td*α*L-jWh*jx-j]=wAm+1x*, which is (ix).
111 Thus, (iii), (iv), (v), (vi) and (viii) implies (ix).
112 Hence the required system of equations and inequalities are:
113 i) q*TMj*Am+1,jhj* wAm+1,j for all j W,
114 ii) q*TMj*Am+1,j wAm+1,j for all j W,
115 iii) [ q*TMj*Am+1,jhj*wAm+1,j] xj* = 0 for all j W,
116 iv) [ q*TMj*Am+1,jwAm+1,j] xj* = 0 for all j W,
117 v) Mx* = d*,
118 vi) *[Am+1x* L- ] = 0,
119 vii) xj* x-j for all j W,
120 viii) [ xj*x-j ] hj* = 0 for all j W.
121 Note that {j| xj* > 0} ≠ , since d* > 0, {j W| xj* > 0} {j| q*TMj*am+1,jhj*wam+1,j = 0}, {j W| xj* > 0} {j W| q*TMj*am+1,jwam+1,j = 0}.
122 Let J = {j| xj* > 0}.
123 Let d be a final demand vector producible by J. Then clearly d {Mx R+m \{0}|x R+n , xj x-j for all j W, Am+1x L- , and xj = 0 for all j J}.
124 Let x(d) solve the following linear programming problem:
125 wAm+1xmin subject to Mx = d, –Am+1x ≥ – L- , –xj ≥ – x-j for all j W, x ≥ 0, xj = 0, if j J. Since J={j| xj*>0} ={j W| xj* > 0}{j W| xj* > 0}{j W| q*TMj*am+1,jhj*wam+1,j = 0}{j W| q*TMj*am+1,jwam+1,j = 0} and xj(d) = 0 for all j J it is clear that [ q*TMj*Am+1,jhj*wAm+1,j]xj(d) = 0 for all j W and [ q*TMj*Am+1,jwAm+1,j]xj(d) = 0 for all j W.
126 Hence, the following system of equations and inequalities are satisfied:
127
  1. Mx(d) = d,
  2. Am+1 x(d) L- ,
  3. xj(d) x-j for all j W,
  4. q*TMj*Am+1,j hj* wAm+1,j for all j W,
  5. q*TMj*Am+1,j wAm+1,j for all j W ,
  6. [ q*TMj*Am+1,jhj*wAm+1,j]xj(d) = 0, for all j W,
  7. [ q*TMj*Am+1,jwAm+1,j]xj(d) = 0, for all j W.
128 Thus x(d) satisfies all the constraints of LP – d and q*, *, solves all the constraints of the DLP – d. Further, xj(d) = 0, if j J.
129 The value of the objective function of LP – d at x(d) is wAm+1x(d) and that of the dual DLP – d at q*, *, is q*Td* L-jWhj*x-j .
130 From (a) we get q*Td = q*TMx(d) and this combined with (f) and (g) gives us [q*Tda* jWhj*xjd]=wAm+1xd.
131 At this point we invoke an assumption about activities operating up to “full capacity”.
132 Assumption (about activities using their entire capacity): Suppose that {j W| xj* = x-j }{j W|xj(d) = x-j }.
133 Now, jWhj*xjd={jW|xj*<x-j}hj*xjd+{jW|xj*= x-j}hj*xjd.
134 Clearly {jW|xj*<x-j}hj*xjd=0 , since hj* = 0 whenever xj*<x-j} .
135 Thus, jWhj*xjd={jW|xj*= x-j}hj*xjd.
136 However, {j W| xj* = x-j }{j W|xj(d) = x-j }.
137 Thus, jWhj*xjd={jW|xj*= x-j}hj*x-j.
138 Since {jW|xj*<x-j}hj*x-j=0, we get jWhj*x-j = jWhj*xj(d) .
139 We already have, [q*Td* L-jWhj*xjd ] = wAm+1x(d).
140 Substituting jWhj*x-j for jWhj*xjd in the above equation gives [q*Tda*-jWhj*x-j]=wAm+1xd.
141 Thus, as is well known in the theory of linear programming, x(d) is an optimal solution for LP – d and so the answer to the question we have posed earlier is in the affirmative, provided {j W| xj* = x-j }{j W|xj(d) = x-j }.
142 From (d) and (e) we get q*TMj*Am+1,j hj* wAm+1,j for all j W and q*TMj*Am+1,j wAm+1,j for all j W .
143 Thus for all j {1, ..., n}, there exists a non-negative real number j such that q*TMjwAm+1,j=α*Am+1,j+εj.
144 Clearly, j = hj* for all j W satisfying q*TMj*Am+1,jhj* wAm+1,j = 0 and j = 0 for all jW satisfying q*TMjα*Am+1,jwAm+1,j=0.
145 Let v R+n be the row vector whose coordinate j is *Am+1,j + j.
146 Since q*TMwAm+1 = v, v is profitable at wage rate w.
147 Hence if M is a weakly productive activity matrix, by Proposition 2 it follows that there exists an equilibrium price-vector p* at the wage rate w and row-vector v.
148 Important Note: v depends on q*, *, which depends on J. Thus p* depends on the producibility of d by activities in J and on the assumption {j W| xj* = x-j }{j W|xj(d) = x-j }.
149 Hence, as mentioned in the first section, there is a clear dependence of the equilibrium price-vector on the final demand vector, unlike the conclusion of Sraffian economics.
150 This proves the following theorem, which is popularly known as the Non-Substitution Theorem.
151 Theorem 1. Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) , suppose that for some producible final demand vector d*, x* is an optimal solution for LP – d*. Let d be a final demand vector producible by J = {j| xj* > 0}. Let x(d) be an optimal solution for the linear programming problem LP – d along with an additional constraint xj = 0 for all j J (i.e., x is producible by J):
152 wAm+1xmin    s.t.Mx=d*,    Am+1xL-,    xjxj*     jW,     xj=0    jJ,    x0.
153 If {jW| xj*=x-j}{jW|xjd=x-j} (i.e., the capacities that are binding at x* continue to remain binding at x(d)), then x(d) solves LP  d.
154 If in addition M is weakly productive, then there exists a price-vector p* known as efficiency price vector, an array of non-negative real numbers and a real number * ≥ 0 – such that:
155
  1. pTMjwAm+1,jhj* *Am+1,j for all j W;
  2. pTMjwAm+1,j *Am+1,j for all j W;
  3. pTMjwAm+1,jhj* = *Am+1,j for all j W with xj* > 0;
  4. pTMjwAm+1,j = *Am+1,j for all j W with xj* > 0 . ■
156 Note. In the statement above, for each j W, hj* could be interpreted as the shadow price of operating the activity j at unit level. So, the shadow price of any activity that operates below capacity at x* is 0, and continues to remain, so even if at x(d) it uses up the entire capacity.
157 An immediate corollary of Theorem 1 is the following “compact” result valid only for (M, ).
158 Corollary of Theorem 1. Given a CLAAM (M, ), suppose that for some producible final demand vector d*, x* is an (a basic) optimal solution for LP – d*. Let d be a final demand vector producible by J = {j| xj* > 0}. Let x(d) be an optimal solution for LP – d along with an additional constraintx is producible by J”. Then x(d) solves LP – d.
159 If in addition M is weakly productive, then there exists a price-vector p* known as efficiency price-vector and a real number * ≥ 0 – such that:
160
  1. pTMjwAm+1,j *Am+1,j for all j {1, …, n};
  2. pTMjwAm+1,j = *Am+1,j for all j with xj* > 0 .
161 Note. In the proof of Theorem 1 presented in the form of a discussion prior to the statements of the two theorems, observe that, since x(d) must belong to R+n \{0} and Am+1 >> 0, it must be the case that wAm+1x(d) > 0.
162 7. Multisector Production Theory for CLAAM
163 The implications of the above analysis for constrained linear activity analysis models when the m manufactured goods are interpreted as m distinct composite commodities in a one-to-one correspondence with m distinct sectors of the economy is best performed with a dynamic (two-period) interpretation of the model discussed here, with production taking place during the current/first period — period 0 and the final demand vector is supplied during a subsequent period- period 1. In such a situation a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) corresponds to the specific case where:
164
  1. there exist non-negative mn matrices B, A such that M = BA;
  2. the entries in the matrices B and A are measured in money units evaluated at producer prices.
165 Thus for I {1, …, m} and j {1, …, n}, aij is the cost of good i required to operate activity j at unit level and bij is the is the monetary of good i produced if activity j is operated at unit level, both measured in producer prices prevailing in period 0.
166 Issues relating to solvability remain intact — the analysis in section four remains unaffected under this new interpretation. What however requires some reformulations are issues related to existence of equilibrium price vector and as a consequence, issues related to efficiency prices via the non-substitution theorems.
167 In the first place, instead of price-vector the concept that is relevant in this context is (sectoral) inflation rate vectors, i.e., the vector of factors by which the period 0 sectoral price indices are individually multiplied to obtain the period 1 price indices.
168 As in section 5, the amount of the only non-produced good called labour that is used as input as well its total initial amount in the economy is measured in physical units.
169 An inflation rate-vector is a vector p R+m \{0}. Let w > 0 denote wage rate of labour.
170 At inflation rate-vector p and wage rate w the profit-vector at the pair (p,w) denoted pp,w=pTBeTAwAm+1, where e is the m-dimensional column vector all entries of which are 1; e is called the sum-vector.
171 A row-vector v R+n is said to be profitable at wage rate w > 0, if there exists q Rm such that qTB=wAm+1+eTA+v.
172 Note. The vector q in the definition of profitable vectors need not be non-negative.
173 An inflation rate-vector p is said to be an equilibrium inflation rate-vector at the wage rate w > 0 and row-vector v R+n if v = (p,w).
174 Instead of the activity matrix being weakly proper, we now require the following property.
175 Weakly proper Output Coefficient Matrix. Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) with M=BA for non-negative matrices A and B, for all pq  R+m and d CS(M,<x-j|jW>) ( R+m \{0})( R+m \{0}) : [pTBqTB implies pTdqTd].
176 This allows us to state and prove the following result.
177 Result 1. Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) with M = B A for non-negative matrices A and B and satisfying weakly proper output coefficient matrix property if v is a profitable row vector at wage rate w > 0. Then there exists an equilibrium inflation rate-vector p at the wage rate w and row-vector v.
178 Note that the solvability aspect of the non-substitution theorem, concerns minimization of aggregate wages or cost of labour, subject to producibility constraint. Hence that aspect of the non-substitution theorem remains intact under the new interpretation. We need to however replace the concept of efficiency prices by efficiency inflation rates.
179 The following result has a proof similar to the one for theorem 1.
180 Result 2. Given a CLAAM (M,<x-j|jW>) with M = B A for non-negative matrices A and B, suppose that for some producible final demand vector d*, x* is an optimal solution for LP – d*. Let d be a final demand vector producible by J = {j| xj* > 0}. Let x(d) be an optimal solution for the linear programming problem LP – d along with an additional constraint xj = 0 for all j J (i.e., x is producible by J):
181 wAm+1xmin     s.t.    Mx=d*,Am+1xL-,xjx-j     jW,    xj=0    jJ,     x0.
182 If {jW| xj* = x-j }{j W|xj(d) = x-j } (i.e., the capacities that are binding at x* continue to remain binding at x(d)), then x(d) solves LP – d.
183 If in addition the Weakly Proper Output Coefficient Matrix property is satisfied, then there exists an inflation rate-vector p* known as efficiency inflation rate vector, an array of non-negative real numbers and a real number * ≥ 0 – such that:
184
  1. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,j hj* *Am+1,j for all j W;
  2. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,j *Am+1,j for all j W;
  3. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,jhj* = *Am+1,j for all j W with xj* > 0;
  4. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,j = *Am+1,j for all j W with xj* > 0 .
185 An immediate corollary of Result 2 is the following compact result valid only for (M, ).
186 So, the shadow price of any activity that operates below capacity at x* is 0, and continues to remain, so even if at x(d) it uses up the entire capacity.
187 Corollary of Result 2. Given a CLAAM (M, ), suppose that for some producible final demand vector d*, x* is an (a basic) optimal solution for LP – d*. Let d be a final demand vector producible by J = {j| xj* > 0}. Let x(d) be an optimal solution for LP – d along with an additional constraint x is producible by J. Then x(d) solves LP – d.
188 If in addition Weakly Proper Output Coefficient Matrix property is satisfied, then there exists an inflation rate-vector p* known as efficiency inflation rate-vector and a real number * ≥ 0 – such that:
189
  1. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,j *Am+1,j for all j {1, …, n};
  2. pTBjeTAjwAm+1,j = *Am+1,j for all j with xj* > 0 .
190 In the case of final demand for services (provided by the service sector) which do not require manufacturing, but are none the less measured in current producer prices, this may imply a difference between producer prices and the prices that consumers are required to pay for the services during the current period.
191 Acknowledgment. This paper was written when I was a Professor at the School of Petroleum Management, PD Energy University, from where I retired on June 5, 2022. An earlier version of this paper was presented (virtually) at a seminar on April 5, 2020, in the department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, IIT-Bombay. I would like to thank K.S. Mallikarjuna Rao for observations about the paper during my presentation. A subsequent version of this paper was presented (virtually) at the 9th International Conference on Matrix Analysis and Applications hosted by University of Aveiro, Portugal from June 15–17, 2022. I wish to the conference participants – in particular Enide Aandrade — for a positive assessment of the paper. I wish to put on record my deep gratitude to Arabinda Tripathy, for appreciative comments and endorsement of the contents, in addition to encouragement for this research — several steps beyond his role as a senior colleague. I would also like to thank an anonymous referee of this journal and Victor Dementiev (Editor-in-Chief) for suggestions towards improvement of this paper. Last but not the least, I wish to express the immense honour I feel in being able to publish this paper in an academically respected journal published in Russia — the birth place of Professor Wassily Leontief — the father of input-output macroeconomics and Professor Leonid Kantorovich — the father of Linear Programming — whose seminal contributions to “applicable mathematical economics” are the ancestors of the work presented in this paper.

Библиография

1. Chander P. (1983). The nonlinear input-output model. Journal of Economic Theory, 30, 219–229.

2. Lahiri S. (2022). The essential appendix on linear programming. Available at: https://www.academia.edu/44541645/The_essential_appendix_on_Linear_Programming

3. Lancaster K. (1968). Mathematical economics. New York: The Macmillan Company.

4. Sandberg I.W. (1973). A nonlinear input-output model of a multisectored economy. Econo-metrica, 41, 6, 1167–1182.

5. Villar A. (2003). The generalized linear production model: Solvability, non-substitution and prod-uctivity measurement. Advances in Theoretical Economics, 3, 1, 1.

Комментарии

Сообщения не найдены

Написать отзыв
Перевести